Prospects for Britain’s socially and territorially fractured polity

02 June 2015

Colin Hay  - Director of SPERI

It’s still a ‘good election to lose, but too important not to win’

Between 24.4% and 27.5%, I reckon, of Britain’s registered voters are passably happy with the outcome of the 2015 General Election – 27.5% if you think SNP supporters are content, 24.4% if you think contentedness is confined to Tory supporters living (almost exclusively, but not quite) south of the border.  The figures would, of course, be lower if one took into account voter non-registration (the growing share of the disproportionately young who not only don’t vote but are absent from the electoral register).

Of course, those figures would have been worse in their way had Labour, as many predicted, emerged to form a minority government with tacit SNP support.  But it didn’t turn out that way – with the effect, perhaps, that between 1 and 2% more are happier than they would otherwise be.  Lucky them!  The point is that, if we didn’t know it already, the 2015 general election confirms that Britain is a socially and territorially fractured polity with an increasingly arcane electoral system.  But these are arguably the least of its problems today.

When I last blogged about the election campaign I did so with a certain sense of foreboding.  I suggested – perhaps in an unconscious attempt to offer some solace to my anticipated future self on election night – that this might not be a good election to win.  But I immediately (and quite rightly) corrected myself.  2015 was, and remains, simply too important an election to lose.  It is that thought that haunts me and that I want to reflect further on now.

2010 also, of course, seemed like a good election to lose.  It was always going to be difficult for the victor to govern and impossible to govern alone in the absence of a clear majority.  No party had a mandate for office and there were all the difficulties of coalition formation, management and maintenance – each a tough proposition.  Austerity, in particular, was likely to prove something of a poison chalice (albeit a largely self-imposed one), especially in the absence of stable growth and in the context of a lingering Eurozone crisis.

But, in practice, it didn’t turn out like that.  In a way, circumstances conspired to help the Coalition government survive to the end of its (newly) fixed five-year parliamentary term.  Labour in opposition was slow to respond to Cameron’s austerity governance and keen to wait for things to unravel.  It certainly never managed to change the terms of the debate and didn’t decide on the detail of its economic pitch to the electorate (to the extent that it had one) until far too late – seeking to make a virtue of comparative silence and waiting (in vain) for the government to dig its own grave.

Above all, it never decided whether a new growth model was needed or if it was best to make do with the old one.  Moreover, Labour’s long leadership contest allowed the Liberal Democrats and the Tories to conspire to pin the blame for the parlous condition of Britain’s public finances on Labour’s alleged fiscal dereliction of duty in the years prior to the crisis (a claim that was palpably ridiculous given the historically low cost of borrowing the government enjoyed, but a charge that nevertheless stuck).  Labour never seized back the initiative and fell, too easily, into a response-mode form of politics.

Perhaps more significantly still, the Liberal Democrats helped the Tories make austerity look normal and moderate.  Cuts to public spending and public investment on the scale and to the time-frame proposed would otherwise have seemed the clear product of ideological zealotry (for a while the official public spending projections had the British state shrinking to a size, relative to GDP, smaller than at any point since the 1930s and well below that of the United States, for example).  In short, without the Liberal Democrats in the Coalition, austerity would have been much more strongly resisted, the polls more volatile and the government far less stable.

So what about 2015?  As an election, it seemed, if anything, like an even tougher proposition – even more of a ‘good election to lose’ perhaps?  It is, again, likely to prove difficult for the government to govern – now, more than anything else, because of a territorially divided polity and the absence of a clear majority for the ruling party other than in the southern half of England (excluding London).  It is bound to be difficult to impose every tightening austerity in a context, still, of fragile growth (and with the pre-election stoking of the housing market arguably responsible for much, if not all, of the growth Britain has enjoyed since 2013).  It is important in this context to note that GDP per capita still remains below pre-crisis levels and in fact has grown at an average of only 1 per cent per annum since 2010.

Moreover, the new Conservative government seems to have little sense of a vision of the route back to stable growth or of the paths to productivity gains or enhanced competitiveness (whatever happened to the vaunted ‘rebalancing’ of the economy?).  Finally, of course, the government has a very difficult set of issues to deal with in the first two years of the parliament – a new settlement for Scotland and an ‘in/out’ referendum on EU membership – and it’s likely to be difficult to deal with one without compromising the other.

A good election to lose then?   Actually, no, not at all.  2015 was too important not to win because of the significance of the issues at stake.  Cameron’s administration, quite simply, could well prove to be the last of a Britain in Europe and the last of a united Britain.  As Tony Payne and I noted in an election-day post, Britain was on the verge of a ‘Brexistential’ crisis.  Post-election, from the perspective of ‘Brexit’ and break-up, the situation unquestionably looks bad.  But how bad exactly?  Consider, first, the worst-case scenario – in fact, there are two (and they are almost equally bad).

Here the Tories mess up the Scotland negotiations – failing to offer enough to the Scottish government (and the SNP) because of the need to appease the Tory right with a resolution of the West Lothian question.  This leaves Scotland with greater powers, but Scottish MPs with no vote on core areas of British economic and social policy (those where Scottish powers have ostensibly been extended but which are still likely to shape significantly the space within which any Scottish administration has to operate).  With the charge of betrayal hanging heavily in the air, the SNP writes a second independence referendum into its manifesto for the 2016 Scottish Parliamentary elections.  It would, of course, need a clear majority (in Scotland’s proportional electoral system) for this to precipitate a second independence vote.  However, in this kind of scenario, that is far from impossible.  Here, then, we find a potential route to break-up without Brexit.

But, even if this doesn’t transpire, we can get to break-up through a different (and more familiar) route.  Here Cameron fails to get much from his attempted EU renegotiation (not enough to appease southern England or Tory backbenchers) and might then, as recently hinted, throw in the towel and campaign for an ‘out’ vote.  Either way, though, the ‘Brexit’ vote is on a knife-edge and UKIP (as the anti-Westminster party) would surely to win the campaign, even if not the referendum itself.  The outcome is likely to prove too close to call.  But the point is that any ‘out’ decision would be decisive and would prompt a second (conceivably, third) Scottish independence referendum.  Here it is ‘Brexit’ that leads to break-up.

These are, of course, the worst-case scenarios.  But arguably things would not have been much better under a minority Labour government with tacit SNP support.  Here, the prospect might have been that, amidst intense media scrutiny and growing ructions between Labour and SNP over austerity, intensified by the attempt to negotiate a new constitutional settlement for Scotland, the Labour minority government falls.  The SNP mops up in Scotland (winning, perhaps, every single seat); and a newly Eurosceptic Tory party makes considerable gains over Labour and UKIP south of the border.  In such a scenario, Labour’s tenure would have been short-lived and would in all likelihood have led to the emergence of a government committed not only to an EU referendum but to ‘Brexit’ itself.  That wouldn’t necessarily have delivered ‘Brexit’ – but one would have been brave to bet against it.

Is it possible to find a more optimistic scenario?  Perhaps – but one has to try quite hard.  Here, the Tories’ perceived economic competence unravels as its austerity agenda is seen not only as swingeing, but at the same time pushes the economy back into recession.  The electorate, unprepared for the extent of the cuts to core services effectively guaranteed (but entirely unspecified) by the Tory manifesto, rebels; this gives a new Labour leadership the chance to overcome its habitual timidity in economic and social policy and develop a new British unity narrative.  This is arguably where this scenario becomes a little less credible.  But, anyway, let’s continue: Labour challenges and overturns the terms of the debate, offering a telling diagnosis of Britain’s growth crisis, galvanising support around a new growth agenda and making deficit and debt reduction conditional on the growth thereby attained.  I may now be stretching the bounds of credulity, but this is what one has to do to find an optimistic scenario.

But the key point is that, for any of this to happen, and to get to such a point in the first place, Labour has to hope that the ‘Brexit’ option will be resisted – that the electorate can be convinced of the economic risk that ‘Brexit’ represents (and to commit itself unambiguously to that outcome).  This genie is, however, already out of the bottle.  I would say that the odds are about 50:50 – and it is that thought that keeps me awake at night.

Related posts

Forecasting inflation amid uncertainty: have we forgotten the dog and the frisbee?

Muhammad Ali Nasir - 18 October 2017

The Bank of England’s inflation forecasts in the period since the Brexit vote have been largely inaccurate – is this because the Bank has forgotten the rule of thumb championed by its own chief economist? This is the fifth post in our series on the impact of uncertainty on social science

Read more

Don’t depoliticise inclusive growth!

Professor Tony Payne - 16 November 2017

The endeavour to set out and implement a new vision for more inclusive growth will fail if it is not treated fundamentally as a matter of political economy, rather than an aspect of social policy

Read more